European Monetary System
institutions in foreign countries
as % of total domestic assets, 1997
In EEA countries In third countries
TOTAL
Branches Subsidiaries Branches
Subsidiaries
AT 2.6 NA 3.7 NA
NA
DE 12.0 7.3 7.8 0.9
27.9
ES 5.5 1.4 2.1 5.9
14.9
FI 5.9 0.3 6.6 0.3
13.1
FR 9.1 6.9 9.4 3.8
29.2
IR 8.3 14.9 1.3 10.1
34.6
IT 7.2 2.7 3.8 1.5
15.2
SE 7.2 NA 5.4 NA
NA
Source: ECB report "Possible effects of EMU on the EU banking
systems in the medium to long term" (February 1999).
Table 3. Concentration: Assets of the five biggest credit
institutions as % of total assets
1985 1990 1997
AT 35.8 34.6 48.3
BE 48.0 48.0 57.0
DE NA 13.9 16.7
ES 38.1 34.9 43.6
FI 51.7 53.5 77.8
FR 46.0 42.5 40.3
IE 47.5 44.2 40.7
IT 20.9 19.1 24.6
NL 69.3 73.4 79.4
SE 60.2 70.02 89.7
UK NA NA 28.0
Source: ECB report "Possible effects of EMU on the EU banking
systems in the medium to long term" (February 1999).
Table 4. Number of branches and subsidiaries of foreign credit
institutions, 1997
From EEA countries From third
countries TOTAL
Branches Subsidiaries Branches
Subsidiaries
AT 6 20 2 11
39
BE 25 16 15 15
71
DE 46 31 31 45
153
ES 33 21 20 6
80
FI 9 0 0 0
9
FR 46 118 43 98
305
IR 18 21 3 7
49
IT 36 4 17 4
61
NL 11 8 11 19
49
SE 14 0 3 1
18
UK 106 18 149 114
387
Source: ECB report "Possible effects of EMU on the EU banking
systems in the medium to long term" (February 1999).
Table 5. Private non-financial enterprises' bonds, credit
institutions' bonds and government bonds outstanding as % of GDP,
1997
Private Credit Government
non-financial institutions' bonds
bonds bonds
AT 2.7 31.1 30.6
BE 10.0 38.3 111.0
DE 0.1 54.6 37.6
ES 2.6 4.5 52.9
FI 3.7 7.1 35.5
IE 0.01 1.6 32.2
IT 1.6 19.4 100.4
NL NA 43.1 53.4
SE 3.6 38.6 46.5
Source: ECB report "Possible effects of EMU on the EU banking
systems in the medium to long term" (February 1999).
Euro and European integration
Speech delivered by Eugenio Domingo Solans,
Member of the Governing Council and the Executive Board of the
European Central Bank,
at the "Euro and Denmark" exhibition in Aalborg, Denmark,
on 10 September 1999
INTRODUCTION
It is a real pleasure for me to participate in the "Euro and Denmark"
exhibition in Aalborg. It is the first time since my appointment as a
member of the Executive Board of the European Central Bank (ECB) in May
1998 that I have had the opportunity to speak in Denmark. Thank you for
your invitation and for asking me to share my views on the euro and on
European integration with investors and experts of this "pre-in" country.
I should like to refer to two main topics. First, and more
extensively, allow me to explain the ECB's view and my own view on the role
of the euro as an international currency. After this I intend to make some
brief comments on the key role that the euro and the Eurosystem are playing
in the process of European economic integration.
Before I begin, I should like to add that it goes without saying that
the institutional position of the ECB - and therefore my own official
position - concerning Denmark's entry to the euro area is one of strict
neutrality. This is an issue which has to be decided by the Danish people,
whenever and in whatever way they deem appropriate.
THE EURO AS AN INTERNATIONAL CURRENCY
The three basic functions of the euro
Every currency fulfils three functions: store of value, medium of
exchange and unit of account. Concerning the first function (store of
value), the euro is used and will increasingly be used as an investment and
financing currency by market players, and as a reserve currency by public
authorities. Regarding the second function of money (medium of exchange),
the euro is used and will increasingly be used as a payment or vehicle
currency for the exchange of goods and services and for currency exchange
itself. It will also have an official use as an intervention currency.
Finally, as regards the third function of any currency (unit of account),
the euro is used and will increasingly be used by economic agents as a
pricing or quotation currency and as a pegging currency by the authorities
responsible for exchange rate issues.
Let me give you some information about the present use of the euro in
each of these areas. I shall first refer to the private use of the euro,
after which I shall consider its official public usage.
The euro as a store of value
The available information seems to confirm that the euro already
plays a significant role as an investment and financing currency in
international financial markets. Without going into precise details (1),
regarding the international debt securities market (money market
instruments, bills and bonds), it can be said that in the first two
quarters of 1999 net international issues denominated in euro amounted to
EUR 83.9 billion, compared with EUR 74 billion for the US dollar and EUR
50.9 billion for former euro area national currencies and ECUs during the
same period of 1998. In other words, in the first two quarters of 1999 net
international issues of debt securities denominated in euro were 13.4%
higher than those denominated in US dollars, and 64.8% higher than those
denominated in former euro area national currencies and ECUs issued during
the same period of last year.
With regard to equity markets, the weight of euro area stock
exchanges in terms of capitalisation ranks a clear second, far behind the
United States.
As to the banking sector, the latest data show that, at the end DX
:>48@>2:0 ?;5=:8T- -#"+ !-+ 1999\DXCODE.HTof March 1999, above 40% of
deposits and loans vis-а-vis non-residents were denominated in euro, with
the share of the US dollar almost as high.
The euro as a medium of exchange
As for the second function of money (medium of exchange), the euro
needs more time to develop as a payment currency for goods and services in
international trade and as a vehicle currency in the foreign exchange
markets. Although no precise data are available at this stage, the value of
world exports denominated in euro is not likely to differ significantly
from that of euro area exports. By contrast, the value of world exports
settled in US dollars is nearly four times as high as that of US exports.
This difference can easily be explained by the combined and reinforcing
effects of network externalities and economies of scale in the use of a
predominant international currency, as is the case with the US dollar.
The euro as a unit of account
The use of the euro as a unit of account (its third general function)
is closely linked to its use for the other two main functions. The use of a
currency as a unit of account is, in a way, the basis for its use as a
store of value or as a medium of exchange. The value stored in euro, or the
payments made in euro, will tend to be recorded in euro. Therefore, we can
conclude that the euro is playing an ever larger role as a unit of account
for all the financial assets linked to the use of the euro as an investment
and financing currency, and has a much less relevant role as a standard for
pricing goods and services, owing to the widespread use of the US dollar as
a payment and vehicle currency in international trade. The convenience of
using a single standard for pricing commodities in the international
markets, allowing traders to make direct comparisons between prices, makes
it difficult for the euro to acquire a significant role in this respect. We
can conclude that the development of the euro as a unit of account will
follow the pace at which the issuers or suppliers of assets, goods or
services priced or quoted in euro obtain a predominant position in the
international markets.
The official use of the euro
The euro also has official uses as reserve, intervention and pegging
currency, all three functions being strongly interrelated in most cases.
With regard to its official use, the euro is currently the second
most international currency after the US dollar, this being a legacy of the
former euro area national currencies.
Compared with the former euro area national currencies, there has
been a technical decline in the share of the euro as a reserve (and,
therefore, as an intervention) currency, mainly owing to the fact that such
former national currencies became domestic assets within the euro area.
However, there are good reasons to expect an increase in international
public use of the euro as a reserve and intervention currency, inasmuch as
the public authorities understand that it is worthwhile to allocate their
foreign reserves among the main international currencies and to give the
euro a relevant share in accordance with its internal and external
stability and the economic and financial importance of the euro area.
In connection with the use of the euro as a pegging currency,
approximately 30 countries outside the euro area currently have exchange
rate regimes involving the euro to a greater or lesser extent. These
exchange rate regimes are: currency boards (Bosnia-Herzegovina, Bulgaria,
Estonia); currencies pegged to the euro (Cyprus, FYROM [the Former Yugoslav
Republic of Macedonia] and 14 African countries in which the CFA franc is
the legal tender); currencies pegged to a basket of currencies including
the euro, in some cases with a fluctuation band (Hungary, Iceland, Poland,
Turkey, etc.); systems of managed floating in which the euro is used
informally as the reference currency (Czech Republic, Slovak Republic and
Slovenia); and, last but not least, European Union currencies pegged to the
euro through a co-operative arrangement, namely ERM II. As you well know,
Denmark and Greece joined ERM II on 1 January 1999 with a ±2.25%
fluctuation band for the Danish krone and a ±15% fluctuation band for the
Greek drachma. Although the euro remains in second position after the US
dollar in terms of its official use, the role of the euro will increase in
the future, without a doubt.
The position of the Eurosystem concerning the international role of
the euro
As a general conclusion stemming from the previous analysis of the
use of the euro in the world economy, we can affirm that the euro is the
second most widely used currency, behind the US dollar and ahead of the
Japanese yen. The private use of the euro as an investment and financing
currency and its official use as a reserve, intervention and pegging
currency are increasing rapidly, while it is developing at a slower pace as
a payment currency in the exchange of goods and services. The use of the
euro as a unit of account is linked to its use as store of value and a
medium of exchange.
Taking the current situation as a starting point, the Eurosystem's
position concerning the future international role of the euro is crystal
clear: we shall not adopt a belligerent stance in order to force the use of
the euro upon the world economy. We are convinced that the use of the euro
as an international currency will come about anyway. It will happen
spontaneously, slowly but inexorably, without any impulses other than those
based on free will and the decisions of market participants, without any
logic other than that of the market. In other words, the
internationalisation of the euro is not a policy objective of the
Eurosystem; it will neither be fostered nor hindered by us. The development
of the euro as an international currency will be a market-driven process, a
free process, which will take place, without a doubt.
Factors determining the importance of the euro in the world economy
We understand that the euro fulfils the necessary conditions to
become a leading international currency with the US dollar and not against
it. There is enough room for both currencies in the world economy.
The necessary conditions for a currency to become an international
currency are based on two broad factors: low risk and large size. The low
risk factor is related to the confidence inspired by the currency and its
central bank, which in turn mainly depends on the internal and external
stability of the currency. The low risk factor tends to lead to
diversification among international currencies, since diversification is a
means to reduce the overall risk; it acts, so to speak, as a centrifugal
force. By contrast, the large size factor relates to the relative
demographic economic and financial importance of the area which supports
the currency; in other words, the "habitat" of the currency. The large size
factor generally tends to lead to centralisation around one or several key
international currencies. It can be seen as a centripetal force, as a
virtuous circle, which will tend to lead to an increasing use of the euro
as an international currency. Let us consider these two factors in more
detail.
The stability of the currency and the credibility of the ECB
The first factor concerns low risk, credibility and stability. The
stability of the euro is a priority for the ECB. Compared with the idea of
stability, the strength of the euro is of lesser importance. This does not
mean that the exchange rate of the euro does not constitute an element to
be considered in the monetary policy strategy of the ECB. However, the
basic factor that will determine the importance of the euro as a widely
used currency in the world economy, in addition to the demographic,
economic and financial dimensions of the euro area, is, without a doubt,
the stability of the new currency, understood as a means to maintain the
purchasing power of savings.
In the global economy the transmission of financial crises by means
of different mechanisms (devaluations of weak currencies, subsequent
increases in interest rates, etc.) is frequently mentioned. Less is said
about the spillover or transmission of positive economic circumstances,
such as stability. The Eurosystem will "export" stability to the rest of
the world economy, and not only in the case of those countries which decide
to tie their currencies, formally or otherwise, to the euro (through the
ERM II or other arrangements). In a global economy the euro area cannot be
an island of stability, but it can transmit its stability to the rest of
the world economy as the links between regions increase.
Stability is the basic requirement for a good currency. It is what we
at the ECB want for the euro. We want a stable euro, not necessarily a
strong euro. In the long term the euro will derive strength from its
stability.
The stability of the euro is the basis for the confidence in and the
credibility of the ECB, without which a large international role for the
euro would be unthinkable. Stability is the proof of the effectiveness of
the institution. Yet in order to be credible it is not sufficient for the
ECB to maintain stability. Other parameters of its action must be
considered: accountability, transparency and communication, a Europe-wide
perspective.
The conditions for the credibility of the euro are certainly
demanding. However, the achievement of these conditions is the aim of all
those of us who have responsibilities in relation to the operation of the
Eurosystem.
The "habitat" of the euro
The second factor, which we have called the large size factor or the
habitat of the euro, is important because without a certain critical mass,
a currency cannot have international relevance, however high its degree of
stability. In addition to quality, quantity is required, as suggested by
the example of the reduced degree of international use of the Swiss franc
in relation to other stable currencies, such as the US dollar or the
Deutsche
Mark until 1998.
The figures relating to the population and the GDP of the euro area
illustrate this. With 292 million inhabitants, its population exceeds that
of the United States (270 million) and that of Japan (127 million). The GDP
of the euro area is, on the other hand, equal to 76% of the GDP of the
United States (EUR 5,774 billion compared with EUR 7,592 billion), though
Страницы: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 18, 19
|