European Monetary System
and was published on 1 December. This value is based on the above-mentioned
definition of price stability and assumes a trend growth in real gross
domestic product of 2-2.5% per annum, as well as a medium-term reduction in
the velocity of circulation of M3 of around 0.5-1% per annum.
We shall not, however, respond mechanistically to deviations from the
reference value for money supply growth, but shall first analyse them
carefully for signals relating to future price developments. Larger or
sustained deviations normally signal risks to price stability.
The second pillar of the monetary policy strategy consists in a
broadly based assessment of the outlook for price developments in the
entire euro area. This assessment will be based on a broad range of
monetary policy indicators. In particular, those variables which could
contain information on future price developments will be analysed in depth.
This analysis should not only provide information on the risks for price
development, but should also help to identify the causes of unexpected
changes in important economic variables.
Some commentators reduced this comprehensive analysis to an inflation
forecast. At the same time, there were demands for the ECB to have to
publish these forecasts in order to satisfy the need for transparency and
accountability. Therefore allow me to make this clear: our strategy
includes a comprehensive analysis of numerous indicators and several
forecasts. To focus on a single official inflation forecast of the
Eurosystem for a specific point in time would in no way accurately reflect
our internal analytical and decision-making process. It would impinge upon
the transparency and clarity of the explanation of our policy. The
publication of an official inflation forecast would also be inappropriate
with regard to the accountability of the ECB, all the more so if this
forecast were based on the assumption of no change in the monetary policy.
The success of the monetary policy of the ECB should primarily be measured
in terms of the maintenance of price stability, not the accuracy of its
conditional forecasts.
The stability-oriented monetary policy strategy of the Eurosystem,
which I have just outlined, constitutes a new and clear strategy. It
emphasises the primacy of the goal of price stability. It takes into
account the inevitable uncertainties concerning economic relationships
inherent in the transition to Monetary Union and the associated systemic
changes and guarantees a high degree of transparency.
Ladies and gentlemen, allow me to comment on certain suggestions on
the orientation of monetary policy which have recently appeared in the
press. Some of these ideas give the impression that monetary policy should
concentrate upon objectives other than price stability, since stable prices
have already been achieved. Inter alia, it has been suggested that the ECB
should react more or less mechanistically to exchange rate developments or
other variables such as, for instance, unit labour costs. Furthermore,
there were calls for monetary policy, by means of reductions in interest
rates, to be used to combat unemployment. Against this background there is
a need to set out clearly the possibilities and limitations of monetary
policy.
Both the reasoning in the Maastricht Treaty and many economic
analyses show that the best contribution the single monetary policy can
make to employment growth is to concentrate on price stability. Without
such a clear approach there is a danger that the public may question the
commitment of the Eurosystem to the goal of maintaining price stability.
Inflation expectations, risk premia and thus long-term rates would rise.
This would increase the cost of the investment which is necessary for a
sustained and lasting rise in the standard of living.
Even under the best possible circumstances, though - i.e. if it
proves to be possible to assure lasting price stability - monetary policy
alone cannot solve the major economic problems of unemployment and future
problems in social security systems.
The Governing Council regards the current high level of unemployment
in the euro area as a matter of great concern. This problem is, however,
predominantly a structural one. It is mainly the result of the rigidities
in the labour and goods markets in the euro area which have arisen partly
through an excessive and disproportionate degree of regulation. Structural
economic reforms, which target the reduction of rigidities, are the
appropriate solution. In those euro area countries in which such reforms
have been implemented unemployment figures have declined markedly. In
addition, I should like to emphasise that moderate wage developments and a
reduction in the burden of tax and social security contributions would
generally help to reduce unemployment. This would be the case even if the
country concerned did not trade heavily with its neighbouring countries.
The positive influence of low taxes and wages on employment clearly has
overall benefits from an international perspective. Such a policy should
not be denounced as "wage dumping".
Turning to the role of exchange rates between the euro and other
important currencies outside the EU, in particular the US dollar, the
Eurosystem has, in formulating its monetary policy strategy, made an
unambiguous choice. This strategy clearly rules out explicit or implicit
objectives or target zones for the euro exchange rate. The pursuit of an
exchange rate objective could easily jeopardise the maintenance of the
objective of price stability and could thereby also be detrimental to real
economic development. Target zones for exchange rates could, for example,
lead to the ECB having to raise interest rates in a recession, despite
increasing downward pressure on prices. I am sure you will agree that such
a mechanistic response to a change in the euro exchange rate would not be
optimal. Furthermore, it is important to remember that we are living in a
world with high capital mobility. Exchange rate agreements, which might
have been possible to implement until recently, are no longer feasible.
The lack of an exchange rate target does not mean that the ECB is
totally indifferent to or takes no account of the euro exchange rate. On
the contrary, the exchange rate will be observed and analysed as a
potentially important monetary policy indicator in the context of the
broadly based assessment of the outlook for price developments. A stability-
oriented monetary and fiscal policy, as stipulated by the Maastricht Treaty
and the Stability and Growth Pact, is an essential pre-condition for a
stable euro exchange rate. Of course, there is no guarantee of lasting
exchange rate stability, not even in a fixed exchange rate regime. Exchange
rate fluctuations are often caused by structural or fiscal policy,
asymmetric real shocks or conjunctural differences. Monetary policy would
clearly be overburdened if it had to prevent such movements in the exchange
rate.
We cannot and shall not gear our monetary policy towards a single
variable, whether a money supply aggregate, an index, the exchange rate or
an inflation forecast for a particular point in time. Nor can we be
involved in any ex ante co-ordination which would entail an obligation to
react to particular commitments or plans. The ECB will always carefully
analyse all relevant indicators. In this context, it is particularly
important that the economic causes of potential risks to price stability in
the euro area are understood as fully as possible. Appropriate monetary
policy decisions also depend upon the causes of unexpected changes in
important economic variables. The Governing Council must, for example, take
a view on whether changes in important indicators are of a temporary or
permanent nature, and whether a demand or supply shock is involved. In our
deliberations we also attempt to take into account how the financial
markets, consumers and firms are expected to react to monetary policy
decisions. I believe few would contest that such a complex analysis cannot
meaningfully be reduced to a more or less mechanistic reaction to a few
variables or a single official forecast.
In addition, concern was often expressed that the Eurosystem would
not act transparently enough. In this context, it was said that a
transparent monetary policy also necessitated the publication of the
minutes of the meetings of the Governing Council and disclosure of the
voting behaviour of the individual members of the Council.
For sound reasons the Governing Council decided not to adopt this
approach. The publication of individual positions could easily lead to
national influence being exerted over the individual Council members. The
members of the Governing Council must not, however, be seen as national
representatives. They decide together on the monetary policy for the euro
area as a whole. The Governing Council has committed itself to go beyond
the reporting and explanatory requirements laid down in the Treaty, which
are among the most comprehensive requirements by international standards.
On the basis of our strategy, after every first meeting in the month
I deliver to the press a detailed explanation of our assessment of the
overall economic situation and, in particular, the outlook for price
stability. The content of this so-called "introductory statement" is very
close to what other central banks refer to as minutes. In this way, the
public receives comprehensive information immediately following the
meetings of the Governing Council. In addition, each month we shall publish
a detailed report on the economic situation and monetary policy throughout
the euro area in our Bulletin. Such rapid information on the results of the
meetings of the Governing Council and the current economic analysis of the
ECB without doubt demonstrates a high degree of openness and transparency.
The most recent monetary policy decisions and operations
Co-operation between the European central banks was always very
close. In the last few months of 1998 the countries participating in the
third stage of Monetary Union co-operated more and more closely. The co-
ordinated reduction in leading rates at the beginning of December 1998
clearly showed that the currency union had begun de facto before the start
of Stage Three. This co-ordinated measure contributed substantially - as we
now know - to the stabilisation of market expectations.
For more than five weeks the ECB has been conducting monetary policy
operations, mainly in the form of reverse open market operations. The main
operation will be carried out at a weekly frequency with a maturity of two
weeks. So far, five such operations have been conducted successfully, at a
fixed interest rate of 3%.
Besides the reverse transactions which constitute the main instrument
for liquidity control and targeting interest rates, the Eurosystem offers
two "standing" facilities: the marginal lending facility and the deposit
facility. These can be accessed by credit institutions via the national
central banks. The marginal lending facility is primarily a safety valve
for short-term liquidity shortages in the banking system and thereby limits
upward movements in money market rates. To some extent, its counterpart is
the short-term deposit facility, which is used to absorb short-term
liquidity surpluses. This forms the lower limit for money market rates. For
the start of Monetary Union the interest rate on the deposit facility was
set at 2% and the rate on the marginal lending facility was set at 4.5%.
As a transitional measure, the Governing Council decided to establish
a narrow corridor of 2.75-3.25% between the rates on the marginal lending
facility and the deposit facility from 4 to 21 January 1999. The intention
was to facilitate the necessary adjustment to the new institutional
environment brought about by the transition to Stage Three. As already
announced, on 21 January 1999 it was decided to return to the rates on the
two "standing" facilities that were set for the start of the single
monetary policy. Since 22 January 1999, therefore, the rate on the deposit
facility has been 2% and the rate on the marginal lending facility has been
4.5%.
A critical factor in this decision was the behaviour of the money
market for the euro area as a whole since the beginning of the year. The
Governing Council established that over time there had been a marked
reduction in the difficulties experienced by some market participants with
the introduction of the integrated money market and, in particular, with
cross-border liquidity flows. All in all, the integration of the money
market in the euro area reached a satisfactory stage only three weeks after
its implementation. In analysing the money market it should be noted that,
inter alia, there can be a marked difference between ECB interest rates and
short-term market rates. On the one hand, market rates may include credit
risk premia, and on the other, expectations may lead to differences between
the two rates.
At its meeting last Thursday the Governing Council confirmed its
earlier assessment of the outlook for price stability. Therefore it was
decided to leave the conditions for the next main refinancing operations,
on 10 and 17 February 1999, unchanged. They will be carried out as volume
tenders at a fixed rate of 3%, the same conditions as the last such
monetary policy operations.
In addition, in recent weeks the first longer-term open market
operations were also conducted, in the form of reverse transactions. These
were carried out on 14 January 1999 in three parallel tender procedures
with maturities of one, two and three months. The fixed rate tender
procedure was used. By contrast with the regular main refinancing
operations, the Eurosystem does not use these longer-term operations to
send signals to the market and therefore usually acts as a price-taker. The
ECB thus gives advance indication of the planned allocation. The interest
rates which arise from these monetary policy operations should therefore be
seen as indicators of prevailing market conditions.
Regular assessment of the monetary, financial and economic situation
To conclude, I should like briefly to report on the Governing
Council’s current assessment of the monetary, financial and economic
situation. On the basis of these assessments the Governing Council decided
last Tuesday to leave interest rates unchanged.
Taking into account the latest monetary data for December 1998, the
three-month moving average of the 12-month growth rate of the monetary
aggregate M3 (for the period from October to December 1998) remained more
or less stable at 4.7%. This value is very close to the reference value set
by the Governing Council. According to our analysis, the evolution of the
money supply shows no risks to price stability. Credit to the private
sector also grew strongly in December last year. Although at present we do
not perceive any inflationary signals, further developments will be very
carefully monitored.
With regard to the broadly based assessment of the outlook for price
developments and the risks to price stability in the euro area, monetary
and financial developments can be seen to indicate a favourable assessment
of the latest monetary policy decisions of the Eurosystem. They indicate
that market participants expect a continuation of the environment of price
stability. Long-term rates fell to new historical lows at the beginning of
1999 and there was an overall downward shift in the yield curve. Therefore,
financing conditions for investment are currently exceptionally favourable.
At present the growth prospects for the euro area are, however, still
marked by the uncertainties relating to the development of the world
economy in 1999. These uncertainties have had a negative impact on
indicators of the economic climate in the euro area. There are widespread
expectations of an economic slowdown in the near future. This deterioration
in the external economic environment can be linked, above all, to the
financial crises in Asia, Russia and Latin America. However, there is a
mixed picture. While the growth rate for industrial production fell up to
November 1998, retail sales figures and consumer confidence have recently
shown positive trends. Furthermore, growth in real gross domestic product
in the euro area was relatively robust in the third quarter of 1998. In the
United States real growth in the fourth quarter actually turned out higher
than expected. Measured against the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices,
the HICP, consumer prices in the euro area rose by 0.8% in December 1998.
This is a tenth of a percentage point lower than in November. This
development is in line with earlier trends. It can be linked, in
particular, to a further decline in energy prices and a weakening in price
increases in industrial goods.
All in all, the above-mentioned economic development and the
available forecasts for 1999 do not indicate any noticeable upward or
downward pressure on prices. Potential upward risks could arise from a
change in the external global economic situation and any associated effects
on the euro area, via import and producer prices. These developments must
be carefully monitored. There is concern that inflationary pressure might
develop in the event of a strong increase in wage prices and an easing of
fiscal policy. Developments in the exchange rate will also be closely
monitored in view of their significance for price developments.
Finally, let me emphasise that the current level of real interest
rates is exceptionally low. If real interest rates are taken simply as the
difference between nominal rates and the current increase in consumer
prices (HICP), short-term real interest rates in January 1999 stood at
2.3%, i.e. around 80 basis points lower than one year ago. Long-term real
rates have fallen even more, by 110 basis points, and stood at 3% in
January. These levels are very low, both compared with other countries and
with historical data. In line with the safe-guarding of price stability,
the current monetary and financial conditions thus clearly support future
economic growth. Monetary policy can do no more than this without
jeopardising the great overall economic advantages of price stability and
its own credibility.
Real structural reforms which increase the flexibility of the labour
markets, as well as a continuation of the moderate increase in wage prices,
would not only ease the burden on monetary policy but would also support
employment growth. This will be all the more true if the deterioration in
the economic situation this year is worse than expected owing to the
Страницы: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 18, 19
|