European Monetary System
of the structural features of the system. For their own purposes, these
central banks also have precise and comprehensive information about the
banks in their respective country. This is obtained either from performing
practical supervisory duties, as in the case of the Bank of Japan or the
Bundesbank; or from the national supervisory authority; or through direct
contacts with the banking industry, as in the case of the Bank of England.
The Banking Supervision Committee is in a good position to co-operate
with the Eurosystem in the collection of information. Indeed, the so-called
BCCI Directive has removed the legal obstacles to the transmission of
confidential information from competent supervisory authorities to "central
banks and other bodies with a similar function in their capacity as
monetary authorities". This includes national central banks and the ECB. Of
course, the provision of supervisory information is voluntary and its
development will have to be based on an agreed view of the central banking
requirements the Eurosystem will have in this field.
V. CRISIS MANAGEMENT
21. In normal circumstances central banking and prudential
supervision have an arm's length distance between them. In crisis
situations, however, they need to act closely together, often in co-
operation with other authorities as well. Charles Goodhart and Dirk
Schoenmaker have made here at the London School of Economics a valuable
contribution to analysing the handling of major banking problems in the
history of industrial countries. One of their conclusions is that, in most
instances, central banks have indeed been involved. Banking problems are so
close to monetary stability, payment system integrity and liquidity
management that this finding hardly comes as a surprise. The advent of the
euro will not, by itself, change this state of affairs.
22. When discussing crisis management, it should not be forgotten
that, while central banks have a direct and unique role to play when the
creation of central bank money is involved, this represents just one
category of emergency action. Another category refers to the injection - by
politically liable Finance Ministries - of taxpayers' money into ailing or
insolvent credit institutions. There is also a third, market-based,
category, consisting of the injection of private money by banks or other
market participants. These three typologies of emergency action all require
the involvement of policy-makers, but they must not be mixed up when
evaluating the existing arrangements. Therefore, before discussing the much
debated question of the lender-of-last-resort, let me briefly comment on
the two, probably less controversial cases where central bankers are not
the providers of extra funds.
23. First, the "private money solution". This market-based approach
is clearly the preferable option, not just to save public funds and avoid
imbalances in public finances, but also to reduce the moral hazard problem
generated by public assistance to ailing institutions. Indeed, policy-
makers are increasingly aware that the expectations of a helping hand can
increase financial institutions' risk appetite in the first place. However,
even when a market-based solution is possible, on the grounds of private
interest, private parties may not be able to reach a solution for lack of
information or co-ordination. Public authorities have therefore an active
role to play for the market solution to materialise. The recent rescue
package co-ordinated by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to prevent the
LTCM hedge fund from collapsing is a good example of public intervention
being used to achieve a private solution.
Acting as a "midwife" in brokering a private sector deal is not the
only example of managing crises without injecting public funds. Banking
supervisors have at their disposal a number of tools to intervene at the
national level to limit losses and prevent insolvency when a bank faces
difficulties. These tools include special audits, business restrictions and
various reorganisation measures.
In the euro area, national supervisors and central banks will
continue to be the key actors in the pursuit of market-based solutions to
crises. The Eurosystem, or the Banking Supervision Committee, would become
naturally involved whenever the relevance of the crisis required it.
24. Second, the "taxpayers' money solution". Taxpayers have been
forced to shoulder banks' losses in the past, when public authorities felt
that otherwise the failure of a large portion of a country's banking system
or of a single significant institution would have disrupted financial
stability and caused negative macroeconomic consequences. In such instances
banks have been taken over by the state, or their bad assets have been
transferred to a separate public entity to attract new private investment
in the sound part of the otherwise failed banks. The US savings & loans
crisis of the 1980s, the banking crises in Scandinavia in the early 1990s
and the current banking crises in Japan and some East-Asian countries are
examples of system-wide insolvency problems that have triggered taxpayers'
support. Crйdit Lyonnais and Banco di Napoli are recent examples of public
support to individual insolvency problems.
The introduction of the euro leaves crisis management actions
involving taxpayers' money practically unaffected. The option of injecting
equity or other funds remains available for the Member States, since these
operations are not forbidden by the Treaty. Nevertheless, the European
Commission will be directly involved in scrutinising and authorising such
actions, since any state aid must be compatible with the Community's
competition legislation. This happened, for example, in the cases of Banco
di Napoli and ‚[pic]Crйdit Lyonnais.
The handling of solvency crises is not within the competence of the
national central banks nor that of the ECB, although national central banks
are likely to be consulted, as they have been in the past.
25. Third, the "central bank money solution". This is the lender-of-
last-resort issue that has brought the Eurosystem under vigorous criticism
by distinguished academics and the IMF's Capital Markets Division of the
Research Department. The criticism has been that the alleged absence of a
clear and transparent mechanism to act in an emergency raises doubts in the
markets about the ability of the Eurosystem to handle crisis situations. It
is said that the uncertainty generated by the present arrangements would
entail new risks, including the possibility of investors requiring an
additional risk premium at times of financial market volatility and,
ultimately, of the credibility of EMU being damaged. Two examples of these
concerns deserve an explicit mention. The IMF "Report on Capital Markets",
September 1998, stated that "it is unclear how a bank crisis would be
handled under the current institutional framework …which is not likely to
be sustainable". Similarly, the first report of the CEPR (Centre for
Economic Policy Research) on monitoring the ECB entitled "The ECB: Safe at
Any Speed?" expressly suggested that the Eurosystem lacks crisis management
capacity and is too rigid to pass the A-Class test to keep the vehicle on
the road at the first steep turn in financial market conditions in Europe.
26. My response to this criticism is threefold. To my mind, the
criticism reflects a notion of lender-of-last-resort operations that is
largely outdated; it underestimates the Eurosystem's capacity to act; and,
finally, it represents too mechanistic a view of how a crisis is, and
should be, managed in practice.
27. The notion of a central bank's lender-of-last-resort function
dates back more than 120 years, to the time of Bagehot. This notion refers
to emergency lending to institutions that, although solvent, suffer a rapid
liquidity outflow due to a sudden collapse in depositors' confidence, i.e.
a classic bank run. A bank could be exposed to depositors' panic even if
solvent because of the limited amount of bank liquidity and an information
asymmetry between the depositors and the bank concerning the quality of
bank's assets that do not have a secondary market value.
Nowadays and in our industrial economies, runs may occur mainly in
textbooks. They have little relevance in reality because, since Bagehot,
many antidotes have been adopted: deposit insurance, the regulation of
capital adequacy and large exposures, improved licensing and supervisory
standards all contribute to the preservation of depositors' confidence and
minimise the threat of a contagion from insolvent to solvent institutions.
A less unlikely case is a rapid outflow of uninsured interbank
liabilities. However, since interbank counterparties are much better
informed than depositors, this event would typically require the market to
have a strong suspicion that the bank is actually insolvent. If such a
suspicion were to be unfounded and not generalised, the width and depth of
today's interbank market is such that other institutions would probably
replace (possibly with the encouragement of the public authorities as
described above) those which withdraw their funds. It should be noted, in
this respect, that the emergence of the single euro money market lowers
banks' liquidity risk, because the number of possible sources of funds is
now considerably larger than in the past.
Given all of these contingencies, the probability that a modern bank
is solvent, but illiquid, and at the same time lacks sufficient collateral
to obtain regular central bank funding, is, in my view, quite small. The
textbook case for emergency liquidity assistance to individual solvent
institutions has, as a matter of fact, been a most rare event in industrial
countries over the past decades.
28. What if this rare event were nevertheless to occur and cause a
systemic threat? The clear answer is that the euro area authorities would
have the necessary capacity to act. This is not only my judgement, but also
that of the Eurosystem, whose decision-making bodies have, as you can
imagine, carefully discussed the matter. I am not saying that we are, or
shall be, infallible; no one can claim such a divine quality. I am saying
that there are neither legal-cum-institutional, nor organisational, nor
intellectual impediments to acting when needed. In stating this, I am aware
that central banks may be the only source of immediate and adequate funds
when a crisis requires swift action, while solvency remains an issue and
failure to act could threaten the stability of the financial system.
In these circumstances the various national arrangements would
continue to apply, including those concerning the access of central banks
to supervisors' confidential information. As is well known, such
arrangements differ somewhat from country to country.
29. The criticism I have referred to also underestimates the
Eurosystem's capacity to act. To the extent that there would be an overall
liquidity effect that is relevant for monetary policy or a financial
stability implication for the euro area, the Eurosystem itself would be
actively involved.
The Eurosystem is, of course, well equipped for its two collective
decision-making bodies (the Board and the Council) to take decisions
quickly whenever needed, whether for financial stability or for other
reasons. This readiness is needed for a variety of typical central bank
decisions, such as the execution of concerted interventions or the handling
of payment system problems. Indeed, it has already been put to work during
the changeover weekend and in the first few weeks of this year.
A clear reassurance about the capacity to act when really needed
should be sufficient for the markets. Indeed, it may even be advisable not
to spell out beforehand the procedural and practical details of emergency
actions. As Gerry Corrigan once put it, maintaining "constructive
ambiguity" in these matters may help to reduce the moral hazard associated
with a safety net. I know of no central bank law within which the lender-of-
last-resort function is explicitly defined.
The question of who acts within the Eurosystem should also be
irrelevant for the markets, given that any supervised institution has an
unambiguously identified supervisor and national central bank. As to the
access to supervisory information, the lack of direct access by the
Eurosystem should not be regarded as a specific flaw of the euro area's
institutional framework, as has been frequently argued, since this
situation also exists at the national level wherever a central bank does
not carry out day-to-day supervision.
30. Finally, the criticism reflects an overly mechanistic view of how
a crisis is, and should be, managed in practice. Arguing in favour of fully
disclosed, rule-based policies in order to manage crises successfully and,
hence, maintain market confidence, is almost self-contradictory. Emergency
situations always contain unforeseen events and novel features, and
emergency, by its very nature, is something that allows and even requires a
departure from the rules and procedures adopted for normal times or even in
the previous crisis. Who cares so much about the red light when there is
two metres of snow on the road? As for transparency and accountability,
these two sacrosanct requirements should not be pushed to the point of
being detrimental to the very objective for which a policy instrument is
created. Full explanations of the actions taken and procedures followed may
be appropriate ex post, but unnecessary and undesirable ex ante.
31. So far, I have focused on the provision of emergency liquidity to
a bank. This is not the only case, however, in which central bank money may
have to be created to avoid a systemic crisis. A general liquidity "dry-up"
may reflect, for example, a gridlock in the payment system or a sudden drop
in stock market prices. The actions of the Federal Reserve in response to
the stock market crash of 1987 is an often cited example of a successful
central bank operation used to prevent a dangerous market-wide liquidity
shortfall. This kind of action is close to the monetary policy function and
has been called the "market operations approach" to lending of last resort.
In such cases, liquidity shortfalls could be covered through collateralised
intraday or overnight credit, or auctioning extra liquidity to the market.
The Eurosystem is prepared to handle this kind of market disturbance.
VI. CONCLUSION
32. In my remarks this evening, I have looked at the euro area as one
that has a central bank which does not carry out banking supervision. This
would be normal, because in many countries banking supervision is not a
task of the central bank. What is unique is that the areas of jurisdiction
of monetary policy and of banking supervision do not coincide. This
situation requires, first of all, the establishment of smooth co-operation
between the Eurosystem and the national banking supervisors, as is the case
at the national level where the two functions are separated. The most
prominent reason for this is, of course, the scenario where the provision
of liquidity from the central bank has to be made in a situation that is
generated by problems of interest to the supervisor. But beyond that, I do
not know any country in which the central bank is not very closely
interested in the state of health of the banking system, irrespective of
its supervisory responsibilities.
33. In my view, we should move as rapidly as possible to a model in
which the present division of the geographical and functional jurisdiction
between monetary policy and banking supervision plays no significant role.
I do not mean necessarily a single authority or a single set of prudential
rules. Rather I mean that the system of national supervisors needs to
operate as effectively as a single authority when needed. While the causes
of banking problems are often local or national, the propagation of
problems may be area-wide. The banking industry is much more of a system
than other financial institutions.
34. I am clearly aware that we are far from having a common
supervisory system. But since the euro has just been launched and will
last, we have to look in prospective terms at what needs to be set in
place. There is no expectation, at least to my mind, that the division of
responsibility in the euro area between the central bank and the banking
supervisory functions should be abandoned. Although the Treaty has a
provision that permits the assignment of supervisory tasks to the ECB, I
personally do not rely on the assumption that this clause will be
activated. What I perceive as absolutely necessary, however, is that co-
operation among banking supervisors, which is largely voluntary but which
finds no obstacles in the existing Directives or in the Treaty, will allow
a sort of euro area collective supervisor to emerge that can act as
effectively as if there were a single supervisor. This is desirable in the
first instance to render the supervisory action more effective against the
background of current and future challenges and, second, to assist the
Eurosystem in the performance of its basic tasks.
TABLES
Table 1. Market share of branches and subsidiaries of foreign
credit institutions as % of total domestic assets, 1997
From EEA countries From third countries
TOTAL
Branches Subsidiaries Branches
Subsidiaries
AT 0.7 1.6 0.1 1.0
3.4
BE 9.0 19.2 6.9 1.2
36.3
DE 0.9 1.4 0.7 1.2
4.2
ES 4.8 3.4 1.6 1.9
11.7
FI 7.1 0 0 0
7.1
FR 2.5 NA 2.7 NA
9.8
IR 17.7 27.8 1.2 6.9
53.6
IT 3.6 1.7 1.4 0.1
6.8
NL 2.3 3.0 0.5 1.9
7.7
SE 1.3 0.1 0.1 0.2
1.7
UK 22.5 1.0 23.0 5.6
52.1
Source: ECB report "Possible effects of EMU on the EU banking
systems in the medium to long term" (February 1999).
Table 2. Assets of branches and subsidiaries of domestic credit
Страницы: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 18, 19
|