U.S. Economy
and dentists males. But even after allowing for those factors, studies
have generally found that, on average, women earn roughly 10 percent less
than men even in comparable jobs, with equal levels of education,
training, and experience.
Analysis of wage discrimination against black Americans leads to similar
conclusions. Specifically, after controlling for differences in age,
education, hours worked, experience, occupation, and region of the
country, wages for black men are roughly 10 percent lower than for white
men, though occupational segregation appears to be less common by race
than by gender. Issues other than wage discrimination are also important
to note for black workers. In particular, unemployment rates for black
workers are about twice as high as they are for white workers. Partly
because of that, a much lower percentage of the U.S. black population is
employed than the white population.
Hispanic workers generally receive wages about 5 percent lower than white
workers, after adjusting for differences in education, training,
experience, and other characteristics that affect workers’ productivity.
Some studies suggest that differences in the ability to speak English are
particularly important in understanding wage differences for Hispanic
workers.
The differences between the earnings of white males and earnings of
females and minorities slowly decreased in the closing decades of the
20th century. Some laws and regulations prohibiting discrimination seem
to have helped in this process. A large part of those gains occurred
shortly after the adoption of the 1964 Civil Rights Act, which among
other things, outlawed discrimination by employers and unions. Many
economists worry that the discrimination that remains may be more
difficult to identify and eliminate through legislation.
Discrimination in competitive labor markets is economically inefficient
as well as unfair. When workers are not paid based on the value of what
they add to employers’ production and profit levels, society loses
opportunities to use labor resources in their most valuable ways. As a
result, fewer goods and services are produced. If employers discriminate
against certain groups of workers, they will pay for that behavior in
competitive markets by earning lower profits. Similarly, if workers
refuse to work with (or for) coworkers of a different gender, race, or
ethnic background, they will have to accept lower wages in competitive
markets because their discrimination makes it more costly for employers
to run their businesses. And if customers refuse to be served by workers
of a certain gender, race, or ethnicity in certain kinds of jobs, they
will have to pay higher prices in competitive markets because their
discrimination raises the costs of providing these goods and services.
Those who are discriminated against receive lower wages and often
experience other forms of economic hardship, such as more frequent and
longer periods of unemployment. Beyond that, the lower wage rates and
restricted career opportunities they face will naturally affect their
decisions about how much education and training to acquire and what kinds
of careers to pursue. For that reason, some of the costs of
discrimination are paid over very long periods of time, sometimes for a
worker’s entire life.
It is clear that there is still discrimination in the U.S. economy. What
is not always so clear is how much that discrimination costs the economy
as a whole, and that it costs not only those who are discriminated
against, but also those who practice discrimination.
Unions
Many U.S. workers belong to unions or to professional associations (such
as the National Education Association for teachers) that act like unions.
These unions and associations represent groups of workers in collective
bargaining with employers to agree on contracts. During this bargaining,
workers and employers establish wages and fringe benefits, such as health
care and pension benefits, for different types of jobs. They also set
grievance procedures to resolve labor disputes during the life of the
contract and often address many other issues, such as procedures for job
transfers and promotions of workers.
Many studies indicate that wages for union workers in the United States
are 10 to 15 percent higher than for nonunion workers in similar jobs and
that fringe benefits for union workers also tend to be higher. That
compensation difference is an important consideration both for workers
thinking about joining unions, and for employers who are concerned about
paying higher wages and benefits than their competitors. In some cases,
it appears that the higher wages and benefits are paid because union
workers are more productive than nonunion workers are. But in other cases
unions have been found to decrease productivity, sometimes by limiting
the kinds of work that certain employees can do, or by requiring more
workers in some jobs than employers would otherwise hire. Economists have
not reached definite conclusions on some of these issues, but it is
evident that there are many other broad effects of unions on the economy.
Unions and collective bargaining in the United States are markedly
different from such organizations and procedures in other industrialized
nations. U.S. unions generally practice what is often described as
business unionism, which focuses mainly on the direct economic interests
of their members. In contrast, unions in Europe and South America focus
more on influencing national policy agendas and political parties.
The different focus by U.S. unions partly reflects the special history of
unions in the United States, where the first sustained successes were
achieved by craft unions representing skilled workers such as carpenters,
printers, and plumbers. These skilled workers had more bargaining power
and were more difficult for employers to replace or do without than
workers with less training. Unions representing these skilled workers
were also able to provide special services to employers that allowed both
the unions and employers to operate more efficiently. For example, craft
unions in large cities often ran apprenticeship programs to train young
workers in these occupations. And many craft unions operated hiring halls
that employers could call to find trained workers on short notice or for
short periods of time.
Most of these craft unions were members of the American Federation of
Labor (AFL), founded in 1886. The strong bargaining position of these
skilled workers, and the fact that these workers typically earned much
higher wages than most other workers, led the AFL unions to focus on
wages and other financial benefits for their members. Samuel Gompers, the
president of the AFL for nearly all of its first 38 years, once
summarized his philosophy of unions by saying, “What do we want? More.
When do we want it? Now.”
By contrast, industrial unions—which represent all of the workers at a
firm or work site, regardless of their function or trade—were generally
not successful in the United States before Congress passed the National
Labor Relations Act of 1935. This law, also known as the Wagner Act after
its sponsor, Senator Robert F. Wagner of New York, changed the way that
unions are recognized as bargaining agents for workers by employers, and
made it easier for unions representing all workers to win that
recognition. The Wagner Act largely put an end to the violent strikes
that often occurred when unions were trying to be recognized as the
bargaining agent for employees at some firm or work site. The act
established clear procedures for calling and holding elections in which
the workers decide whether they want to be represented by a union, and if
so by which union. The Wagner Act also established a government agency
known as the National Labor Relations Board (NLRB) to hear charges of
unfair labor practices. Either employees or employers may file charges of
unfair labor practices with the NLRB.
After the Wagner Act was passed, the number of workers who belonged to
unions increased rapidly. This trend continued through World War II (1939-
1945), when unions successfully negotiated more fringe benefits for their
members. These fringe benefits were partly a result of wage and price
controls established during the war, which made large wage increases
impossible. In the 1950s union strength continued to grow, and the
national association of industrial unions, known as the Congress of
Industrial Organization (CIO) merged with the AFL.
Since the late 1970s, total union membership has fallen. The percentage
of the U.S. labor force that belongs to unions has decreased dramatically
in the last half of the 20th century, from more than 25 percent in the
mid-1950s to 14 percent in 1997. A number of reasons explain the decline
in union representation of the U.S. labor force. First, unions are
traditionally strong in manufacturing industries, but since the 1950s
manufacturing has accounted for a smaller percentage of overall
employment in the U.S. economy. Employment has grown more rapidly in the
service sector, particularly in professional services and white-collar
jobs. Unions have not had as much success in acquiring new members in the
service sector, with the exception of government employees.
Union membership has also declined as the government established laws and
regulations that mandate for all workers many of the benefits and
guarantees that unions had achieved for their members. These mandates
include minimum wage, workplace safety, higher pay rates for overtime,
and oversight of the management of pension funds if employers fund or
partially fund pensions.
Third, many U.S. firms have become more aggressive in opposing the
recognition of unions as bargaining agents for their employees, and in
dealing with confrontations involving existing unions. For example, it is
increasingly common for firms to hire permanent replacement workers if
strikes occur at a firm or work site.
Finally, workers with college degrees held a larger percentage of jobs in
the U.S. economy in the late 1990s than in earlier decades. These workers
are more likely to be in jobs with some level of managerial
responsibilities, and less likely to think of themselves as potential
union members.
Unions, however, continue to play many valuable roles in representing
their members on economic issues. Equally or perhaps more importantly,
unions provide workers with a stronger voice in how work is done and how
workers are treated. This is particularly true in jobs where it is
difficult to identify clearly how much an individual worker contributes
to total output in the production process. During the 1990s, many U.S.
manufacturing firms adopted team production methods, in which small
groups of workers function as a team. Any member of the team can suggest
ideas for different ways of doing jobs. But management is likely to
consider more carefully those that are recommended by the union or have
union support. Workers may also be more willing to present ideas for job
improvements to union representatives than to managers. In some cases,
workers feel that the union would consider how the changes can be made
without reducing jobs, wages, or other benefits.
Unemployment
A persistent problem for the U.S. economy and some of its workers is
unemployment—not being able to find a job despite actively looking for
work for at least 30 consecutive days. There are three major kinds of
unemployment: frictional, cyclical, and structural. Each type of
unemployment has different causes and consequences, and so public
policies designed to reduce each type of unemployment must be different,
too.
Frictional unemployment occurs as a result of labor mobility, when
workers change jobs or wait to begin a new job. Labor mobility is, in
general, a good thing for workers and the economy overall. It allows
workers to look for the best available job for which they are qualified
and lets employers find the best-qualified people for their job openings.
Because this searching and matching by employees and employers takes
time, on any given day in a market economy there will be some workers who
are looking for a new job, or waiting to begin a job. Even when
economists describe the economy as being at full employment there will be
some frictional unemployment (as much as 5 to 6 percent of the labor
force in some years). This kind of unemployment is generally not a major
economic problem.
Cyclical unemployment occurs when the economy goes into a recession. The
basic causes of cyclical unemployment are decreases in the levels of
consumption, investment, or government spending in the economy, or a
decrease in the demand for goods and services exported to other
countries. As national spending and production levels fall, some
employers begin to lay off workers. Cyclical unemployment varies greatly
according to the health of the economy. Some of the highest unemployment
rates for the last decades of the 20th century took place during the
recession of 1982 to 1983, when unemployment levels reached almost 10
percent. The highest U.S. unemployment rate of the 20th century occurred
in 1933, when the Great Depression left almost 25 percent of the labor
force without work.
Sometimes the government can use monetary or fiscal policies to increase
spending by businesses and households, for instance by cutting taxes. Or
the government can increase its own spending to fight this kind of
unemployment. . Perhaps the most famous example of this kind of tax cut
in the United States was the one designed in 1963 and passed in 1964 by
the administrations of U.S. president John F. Kennedy and his successor,
Lyndon B. Johnson.
Structural unemployment occurs when people who are looking for jobs do
not have the education or skills to fill the jobs that are currently
available. Most policies designed to reduce structural unemployment
provide training programs for these workers, or subsidize education and
training programs available from colleges and universities, technical
schools, or businesses. In some cases, the government provides support
for retraining when increased competition from imported goods and
services puts U.S. workers out of work or when factories are shut down
because production is moved to another state or country.
Unemployment rates also vary sharply by occupation and educational
levels. As a group, workers with college degrees experience far lower
unemployment rates than workers with less education. In 1998 the
unemployment rate for U.S. workers who had not graduated from high school
was 7.1 percent; for high school graduates, the rate was 4.0 percent; for
those with some college the rate was 3.0 percent; and for college
graduates the unemployment rate was only 1.8 percent.
Income Inequality
Another issue involving the operation of labor markets in the U.S.
economy has been the growing difference between the earnings of high-
income and low-income workers at the end of the 20th century. From 1977
to 1997, families who make up the top 20 percent of income groups have
seen their money income rise from 40.9 percent of the national income to
47.2 percent. Over the same period, families in the lowest 20 percent of
income groups have experienced a decline from 5.5 percent of the national
income to 4.2 percent. This trend is the result of several factors.
Wages for skilled workers, those with more education and training, have
increased quickly because the supply of these workers in the U.S. has not
risen as quickly as demand for these workers. In addition, wages for
unskilled labor in the United States have been held down more than in
other nations as a result of U.S. immigration policies. The United States
has admitted a larger number of unskilled workers than other
industrialized nations. Other countries often consider job market factors
more heavily in determining who will be allowed to immigrate. As a
result, the supply of unskilled workers in the United States has
increased faster than in other countries, pushing wages in low-paying
jobs lower.
Finally, government assistance programs for low-income families tend to
be more extensive and generous in other industrialized market economies
than they are in the United States. That is perhaps one of the reasons
that workers in those countries are less willing to accept jobs that pay
lower wages, and why unemployment rates in those countries are
substantially higher than they are in the United States. The exact
relationship between those factors has not been determined, however.
It is clear that it has become increasingly difficult for U.S. workers
who have not at least completed high school to achieve a high or moderate
level of income. In 1996 the average annual income for graduates of four-
year colleges was $63,127 for males and $41,339 for females, while the
average annual income for those who did not graduate from high school was
only $25,283 for males and $17,313 for females.
GOVERNMENT AND THE ECONOMY
Although the market system in the United States relies on private
ownership and decentralized decision-making by households and privately
owned businesses, the government does perform important economic
functions. The government passes and enforces laws that protect the
property rights of individuals and businesses. It restricts economic
activities that are considered unfair or socially unacceptable.
In addition, government programs regulate safety in products and in the
workplace, provide national defense, and provide public assistance to
some members of society coping with economic hardship. There are some
products that must be provided to households and firms by the government
because they cannot be produced profitably by private firms. For example,
the government funds the construction of interstate highways, and
operates vaccination programs to maintain public health. Local
governments operate public elementary and secondary schools to ensure
that as many children as possible will receive an education, even when
their parents are unable to afford private schools.
Other kinds of goods and services (such as health care and higher
education) are produced and consumed in private markets, but the
government attempts to increase the amount of these products available in
the economy. For yet other goods and services, the government acts to
decrease the amount produced and consumed; these include alcohol,
tobacco, and products that create high levels of pollution. These special
cases where markets fail to produce the right amount of certain goods and
services mean that the government has a large and important role to play
in adjusting some production patterns in the U.S. economy. But economists
and other analysts have also found special reasons why government
Страницы: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12
|