U.S. Economy
currency for the Federal Reserve System. The bills are introduced into
circulation when commercial banks use their reserves to buy currency from
the Federal Reserve Bank.
Second, the regional Federal Reserve banks transfer funds for checks that
are deposited by a bank in one part of the country, but were written by
someone who has a checking account with a bank in another part of the
country. Millions of checks are processed this way every business day.
Third, the regional Federal Reserve Banks collect and analyze data on the
economic performance of their regions, and provide that information and
their analysis of it to the national Federal Reserve System. Each of the
12 regions served by the Federal Reserve banks has its own economic
characteristics. Some of these regional economies are concerned more with
agricultural issues than others; some with different types of
manufacturing and industries; some with international trade; and some
with financial markets and firms. After reviewing the reports from all
different parts of the country, the national Federal Reserve System then
adopts policies that have major effects on the entire U.S. economy.
By far the most important function of the Federal Reserve System is
controlling the nation’s money supply and the overall availability of
credit in the economy. If the Federal Reserve System wants to put more
money in the economy, it does not ask the Treasury to print more dollar
bills. Remember, much more money is held in checking and savings accounts
than as currency, and it is through those deposit accounts that the
Federal Reserve System most directly controls the money supply. The
Federal Reserve affects deposit accounts in one of three ways.
First, it can allow banks to hold a smaller percentage of their deposits
as reserves at the Federal Reserve System. A lower reserve requirement
allows banks to make more loans and earn more money from the interest
paid on those loans. Banks making more loans increase the money supply.
Conversely, a higher reserve requirement reduces the amount of loans
banks can make, which reduces or tightens the money supply.
The second way the Federal Reserve System can put more money into the
economy is by lowering the rate it charges banks when they borrow money
from the Federal Reserve System. This particular interest rate is known
as the discount rate. When the discount rate goes down, it is more likely
that banks will borrow money from the Federal Reserve System, to cover
their reserve requirements and support more loans to borrowers. Once
again, those loans will increase the nation’s money supply. Therefore, a
decrease in the discount rate can increase the money supply, while an
increase in the discount rate can decrease the money supply.
In practice, however, banks rarely borrow money from the Federal Reserve,
so changes in the discount rate are more important as a signal of whether
the Federal Reserve wants to increase or decrease the money supply. For
example, raising the discount rate may alert banks that the Federal
Reserve might take other actions, such as increasing the reserve
requirement. That signal can lead banks to reduce the amount of loans
they are making.
The third way the Federal Reserve System can adjust the supply of money
and the availability of credit in the economy is through its open market
operations—the buying or selling of government bonds. Open market
operations are actually the tool that the Federal Reserve uses most often
to change the money supply. These open-market operations take place in
the market for government securities. The U.S. government borrows money
by issuing bonds that are regularly auctioned on the bond market in New
York. The Federal Reserve System is one of the largest purchasers of
those bonds, and the bank changes the amount of money in the economy when
it buys or sells bonds.
Government bonds are not money, because they are not generally accepted
as final payment for goods and services. (Just try paying for a hamburger
with a government savings bond.) But when the Federal Reserve System pays
for a federal government bond with a check, that check is new
money—specifically, it represents a loan to the government. This loan
creates a higher balance in the government’s own checking account after
the funds have been transferred from the privately owned Federal Reserve
Bank to the government. That new money is put into the economy as soon as
the government spends the funds. On the other hand, if the Federal
Reserve sells government bonds, it collects money that is taken out of
circulation, since the bonds that the Federal Reserve sells to banks,
firms, or households cannot be used as money until they are redeemed at a
later date.
The Wall Street Journal and other financial media regularly report on
purchases of bonds made by the Federal Reserve and other buyers at
auctions of U.S. government bonds. The Federal Reserve System itself also
publishes a record of its buying and selling in the bond market. In
practice, since the U.S. economy is growing and the money supply must
grow with it to keep prices stable, the Federal Reserve is almost always
buying bonds, not selling them. What changes over time is how fast the
Federal Reserve wants the money supply to grow, and how many dollars
worth of bonds it purchases from month to month.
To summarize the Federal Reserve System’s tools of monetary policy: It
can increase the supply of money and the availability of credit by
lowering the percentage of deposits that banks must hold as reserves at
the Federal Reserve System, by lowering the discount rate, or by
purchasing government bonds through open market operations. The Federal
Reserve System can decrease the supply of money and the availability of
credit by raising reserve ratios, raising the discount rate, or by
selling government bonds.
The Federal Reserve System increases the money supply when it wants to
encourage more spending in the economy, and especially when it is
concerned about high levels of unemployment. Increasing the money supply
usually decreases interest rates—which are the price of money paid by
those who borrow funds to those who save and lend them. Lower interest
rates encourage more investment spending by businesses, and more spending
by households for houses, automobiles, and other “big ticket” items that
are often financed by borrowing money. That additional spending increases
national levels of production, employment, and income. However, the
Federal Reserve Bank must be very careful when increasing the money
supply. If it does so when the economy is already operating close to full
employment, the additional spending will increase only prices, not output
and employment.
Effect of Monetary Policies on the U.S. Economy
The monetary policies adopted by the Federal Reserve System can have
dramatic effects on the national economy and, in particular, on financial
markets. Most directly, of course, when the Federal Reserve System
increases the money supply and expands the availability of credit, then
the interest rate, which determines the amount of money that borrowers
pay for loans, is likely to decrease. Lower interest rates, in turn, will
encourage businesses to borrow more money to invest in capital goods, and
will stimulate households to borrow more money to purchase housing,
automobiles, and other goods.
But the Federal Reserve System can go too far in expanding the money
supply. If the supply of money and credit grows much faster than the
production of goods and services in the economy, then prices will
increase, and the rate of inflation will rise. Inflation is a serious
problem for those who live on fixed incomes, since the income of those
individuals remains constant while the amount of goods and services they
can purchase with their income decreases. Inflation may also hurt banks
and other financial institutions that lend money, as well as savers. In a
period of unanticipated inflation, as the value of money decreases in
terms of what it will purchase, loans are repaid with dollars that are
worth less. The funds that people have saved are worth less, too.
When banks and savers anticipate higher inflation, they will try to
protect themselves by demanding higher interest rates on loans and
savings accounts. This will be especially true on long-term loans and
savings deposits, if the higher inflation is considered likely to
continue for many years. But higher interest rates create problems for
borrowers and those who want to invest in capital goods.
If the supply of money and credit grows too slowly, however, then
interest rates are again likely to rise, leading to decreased spending
for capital investments and consumer durable goods (products designed for
long-term use, such as television sets, refrigerators, and personal
computers). Such decreased spending will hurt many businesses and may
lead to a recession, an economic slowdown in which the national output of
goods and services falls. When that happens, wages and salaries paid to
individual workers will fall or grow more slowly, and some workers will
be laid off, facing possibly long periods of unemployment.
For all of these reasons, bankers and other financial experts watch the
Federal Reserve’s actions with monetary policy very closely. There are
regular reports in the media about policy changes made by the Federal
Reserve System, and even about statements made by Federal Reserve
officials that may indicate that the Federal Reserve is going to change
the supply of money and interest rates. The chairman of the Federal
Reserve System is widely considered to be one of the most influential
people in the world because what the Federal Reserve does so dramatically
affects the U.S. and world economies, especially financial markets.
LABOR AND LABOR MARKETS
Labor includes work done for employers and work done in a person’s own
household, but labor markets deal only with work that is done for some
form of financial compensation. Labor markets include all the means by
which workers find jobs and by which employers locate workers to staff
their businesses. A number of factors influence labor and labor markets
in the United States, including immigration, discrimination, labor
unions, unemployment, and income inequality between the rich and poor.
The official definition of the U.S. labor force includes people who are
at least 16 years old and either working, waiting to be recalled from a
layoff, or actively looking for work within the past 30 days. In 1998 the
U.S. labor force included nearly 138 million people, most of them working
in full-time or part-time jobs.
Most people in the United States receive their income as wages and
salaries paid by firms that have hired individuals to work as their
employees. Those wages and salaries are the prices they receive for the
labor services they provide to their employers. Like other prices, wages
and salaries are determined primarily by market forces.
Labor Supply and Demand
The wages and salaries that U.S. workers earn vary from occupation to
occupation, across geographic regions, and according to workers’ levels
of education, training, experience, and skill. As with goods and services
purchased by consumers, labor is traded in markets that reflect both
supply and demand. In general, higher wages and salaries are paid in
occupations where labor is more scarce—that is, in jobs where the demand
for workers is relatively high and the supply of workers with the
qualifications and ability to do that work is relatively low. The demand
for workers in particular occupations depends largely on how much the
work they do adds to a firm’s revenues. In other words, workers who
create more products or higher-priced products will be worth more to
employers than workers who make fewer or less valuable products. The
supply of workers in any occupation is affected by the amount of time and
effort required to enter that occupation compared to other things workers
might do.
Workers seeking higher wages often learn skills that will increase the
likelihood of finding a higher-paying job. The knowledge, skills, and
experience a worker has acquired are the worker’s human capital.
Education and training can clearly increase workers’ human capital and
productivity, which makes them more valuable to employers. In general,
more educated individuals make more money at their jobs. However, a
greater level of education does not always guarantee higher wages.
Certain professions that demand a high level of education, such as
teaching elementary and secondary school, are not high-paying. Such
situations arise when the number of people with the training to do that
job is relatively large compared with the number of people that employers
want to hire. Of course this situation can change over time if, for
example, fewer young people choose to train for the profession.
Supply and demand factors change in labor markets, just as they do in
markets for goods and services. As a result, occupations that paid high
wages and salaries in the past sometimes become outdated, while entirely
new occupations are created as a result of technological change or
changes in the goods and services consumers demand. For example,
blacksmiths were once among the most skilled workers in the United
States; today, computer programmers and software developers are in great
demand.
The process of creative destruction carries over from product markets to
labor markets because the demand for particular goods and services
creates a demand for the labor to produce them. Conversely, when the
demand for particular goods or services decreases, the demand for labor
to produce them will also fall. Similarly, when new technologies create
new products or new ways of producing existing products, some workers
will have new job opportunities, but other workers might have to retrain,
relocate, or take new jobs.
Factors Affecting Labor Markets
Changes in society and in the makeup of the population also affect labor
markets. For example, starting in the 1960s it became more common for
married women to work outside the home. Unprecedented numbers of
women—many with little previous job experience and training—entered the
labor markets for the first time during the 1970s. As a result, wages for
entry-level jobs were pushed down and did not rise as rapidly as they had
in the past. This decline in entry-level wages was further fueled by huge
numbers of teens who were also entering the labor market for the first
time. These young people were the children of the baby boom of 1946 to
1964, a period in which the birth rate increased dramatically in the
United States. So, two changes—one affecting women’s roles in the labor
market, the other in the makeup of the age of the workforce—combined to
affect the labor market.
The baby boomers’ effects have continued to reverberate through the U.S.
economy. For example, starting salaries for people with college degrees
became depressed when large numbers of baby boomers started graduating
from college. And as workers born during the boom have aged, the work
force in the United States has grown progressively older, with the
percentage of workers under the age of 25 falling from 20.3 percent in
1980 to 14.3 percent in 1997.
By the 1990s, the women and baby boomers who first entered the job market
in the 1970s had acquired more experience and training. Therefore, the
aging of the labor force was not affecting entry-level jobs as it once
did, and starting salaries for college graduates were rising rapidly
again. There will be, however, other kinds of labor market and public
policy issues to face when the baby boomers begin to retire in the early
decades of the 21st century.
Immigration
Labor markets in the United States have also been significantly affected
by the immigration of families and workers from other nations. Most
families and workers in the United States can trace their heritage to
immigrants. In fact, before the 20th century, while the United States was
trying to settle its frontiers, it allowed essentially unlimited
immigration. see Immigration: A Nation of Immigrants. In these periods
the U.S. economy had more land and other natural resources than it was
able to use, because labor was so scarce. Immigration served as one of
the main remedies for this shortage of labor.
Generally, immigration raises national output and income levels. These
changes occur because immigration increases the number of workers in the
economy, which allows employers to produce more goods and services.
Capital resources in the economy may also become more valuable as
immigration increases. The number of workers available to work with
machines and tools increases, as does the number of consumers who want to
buy goods and services. However, wages for jobs that are filled by large
numbers of immigrants may decrease. This wage decline stems from greater
competition for these jobs and from the fact that many immigrants are
willing to work for lower wages than other U.S. workers.
Immigration into the United States is now regulated by a system of quotas
that limits the number of immigrants who can legally enter the country
each year. In 1964 Congress changed immigration policies to give
preference to those with families already in the United States, to
refugees facing political persecution, and to individuals with other
humanitarian concerns. Before that time, more weight had been placed on
immigrants’ labor-market skills. Although this change in policy helped
reunite families, it also increased the supply of unskilled labor in the
nation, especially in the states of California, Florida, and New York. In
1990 Congress modified the immigration legislation to set a separate
annual quota for immigrants with job skills needed in the United States.
But people with family members who are already U.S. citizens remain the
largest category of immigrants, and U.S. immigration law still puts less
focus on job skills than do immigration laws in many other market
economies, including Canada and many of the nations of Western Europe.
Discrimination
Women and many minorities have long faced discrimination in U.S. labor
markets. Employed women earn less, on average, than men with similar
levels of education. In part this wage disparity reflects different
educational choices that women and men have made. In the past, women have
been less likely to study engineering, sciences, and other technical
fields that generally pay more. In part, the wage differences result from
women leaving the job market for a period of years to raise children.
Another reason for the disparity in wages between men and women is that
there is still a considerable degree of occupational segregation between
males and females—for example, nurses are much more likely to be females
Страницы: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12
|